Banker’s bonuses

The latest missive to emerge from the European Union in its effort to control the risks that banks pose, has been to curb the amount of bonus that can be paid to the employee of a bank.  We have yet to see the detail of how this will operate in practice and what loopholes might be identified to maintain the earning power of executives,  but the creation of this restriction is a reflection of the impotence of shareholders in large businesses to exercise their rights as owners of these businesses.

To a large extent this impotence has arisen because those that exercise the shareholders’ powers whether through proxies or directly, tend to be financial institutions themselves, with similar interests and conflicts.  These financial institutions are not the ultimate owners of these interests because the chain of ownership extends even beyond pension vehicles – often identified as the largest owners of equity around the world – to the wider general public, who have little awareness of this.  This means that items such as remuneration get waived through without too much challenge – because market practice is accepted as the status quo.

But governments as investors have also been reluctant to challenge the status quo.  The reasons for this are less clear because as significant and controlling shareholders, they can very easily replace a board that was not acting in their interests.  But they have chosen not to flex their muscle in this manner.   This can in part be explained because governments as shareholders are also primarily interested in the value of their shareholdings upon exit, rather than income, because this is how an assessment will be made on the success of the government’s strategy and how much it will have ultimately cost the tax payer to bail out ‘too big to fail’ institutions.

In a capitalist economy, wealth creation needs to be rewarded.  Shareholders as owners of businesses should be free to choose how they remunerate and reward those who work for them.  The nature of shareholding has however, changed over the years.  Shareholders have gradually become a fragmented body of owners and this inability to act collectively in their own interests has resulted in them ceding their ability to influence outcomes, so that executives in a business have been able to reward themselves handsomely before passing on any income to shareholders.  These executives of course have an interest in the capital value of shares – to which they do pay keen attention – but true income generation for them as stakeholders, as opposed to capital wealth, has been through bonuses rather than the declaration of dividends.  

The nature of capital markets has therefore changed fundamentally in this respect with the balance of power shifting to the executives.  Shareholders have only themselves to blame in allowing this to have come to pass, but this is largely because the nature of share ownership has changed.   Shares increasingly function as instruments to measure capital value whether for secondary trading, price discovery and transparency or as exit strategies for investors and entrepreneurs rather than for  primary capital raising or as income generating assets.  Of course the shareholder base has also become disparate so that collective action against a board has become more difficult.  Regulations surrounding take-overs such as in relation to concert parties, complicate matters further.  

Activist investment managers recognise this and use their shareholdings in an effort to rectify the imbalance of power that they see – but they too are generally short term investors looking to extract value for their own investors in order to earn management and performance fees.

Difficulties around the regulation of public primary offerings have also resulted in capital being raised through means other than equity and there is increasing use of shadow banking structures and private equity type deals which make expensive charges for these facilities and take company assets as collateral to protect their interests.

Where shareholders are actively engaged in the remuneration process there should be no need for ceilings to be imposed on remuneration.   The chances are that such regulations are likely to drive these remuneration structures offshore to non EU locations and make transparency on these matters even more opaque than they currently are.   Rather than trying to regulate remuneration arrangements, it seems more appropriate to think about how investor engagement can be rekindled to become a more valuable process than the self serving interests of institutional investors who are only acting on behalf of the ultimate owners of these assets.

As ever the devil will be in the detail.

The basic intention of the rule is to curb excessive risk-taking.  The European bureaucrats have decided that this can be controlled by imposing a basic salary-to-bonus ratio of 1:1 but permitting this to be raised to a maximum of 1:2 with the approval of shareholders. This higher ratio would require the votes of at least 65% of shareholders owning half the shares represented, or of 75% of votes if there is no quorum.

In order to encourage a long-term view, if the bonus is increased above 1:1, then a quarter of the whole bonus will be deferred for at least five years.

In order to come into effect,  this proposal must be approved by member states and the European Parliament plenary.  The vote is expected to be taken in the April 2013 session.  If approved, member states would need to include these rules in their national laws by 1 January 2014.

If the vote results in approval for the proposal, then the second half of 2013 may provide some interesting restructuring opportunities for lawyers as they consider how these restrictions need to be addressed by their clients.   

©Jaitly LLP